Many economists are now saying what I
have been arguing for some time — the
present economic slowdown is structural.
It is not caused by a downturn in the business cycle.
Therefore, countercyclical policies are not appropriate to address the slowdown.
While this is immediately clarifying for policymakers, a structural slowdown can be variously interpreted depending on one’s analytical framework and
understanding of the ground situation.
For some, “structural” means that sectors that
have contributed to growth in the past face sectorspecific impediments. Addressing these would
involve sector-level policy interventions, for example,
addressing questions of credit access or correcting
adverse policies. This is currently the discussion about
the automobile sector, for example.
At the macro level, a structural slowdown is typically seen as a supply-side problem.
Institutional or other impediments
to investment are identified, and corrective actions are undertaken. So,
economists advocate factor market
(such as land and labour market),
financial market (credit or capital
market) and regulatory reforms to
address the situation. The question
of demand deficiency is seen as a
cyclical phenomenon.
However, this view has only gathered prominence since the rise to
dominance of supply-side economics
and has, oddly, persisted even when such dominance
has globally withered since 2008. Explicating the
structural demand problem is important to address
the contemporary India-specific economic situation1.
I have previously argued2 that the Indian economy, since 1991, has grown largely by meeting the
consumption demands of the top 10 per cent to 15
per cent of the Indian population. This is reflected
in the fact that “leading indicators” of Indian economic growth are largely about what these people
consume — automobiles, FMCG, consumer
durables, financial services, etc.
Post 1991, there was a shift in relative prices to
facilitate this growth. Here’s a clarifying illustration.
My salary as a young college lecturer in 1988 was
~36,000 per annum. The cheapest car cost ~1,50,000
(four years’ salary), an air conditioner ~20,000 (seven months’ salary), and a Bombay-Delhi air ticket
~3,000 (one month’s salary). Today, the same job
earns ~7,50,000 per annum. The same goods can
now be purchased with six months’, 10 days’, and
one day’s salary, respectively.
This remarkable shift in relative prices fuelled
domestic demand. Private investment responded to
this spurt. This led to a virtuous cycle of growth with
the production structure shifting towards capitalintensive goods consumed by the top 15 per cent. This
was buffeted by welfare interventions (like MGNREGS) and a middle-class housing boom, which bolstered construction employment. Exports and agricultural performance, occasionally, complemented
domestic demand. High growth expanded fiscal
space, which was used to provide universal merit
goods and subsidised food, reducing poverty.
This model is unlikely to sustain in the medium
term but the current slowdown
indicates that its limits seem to
have impacted the economy sooner.
The demand of the top income
deciles is satiating but those earning less (one to three times the
minimum wage) are not able to
afford the things that the “leading
indicators” measure. Sectors that
have hitherto been the engine of
growth are now plateauing. But
investment is depressed because
it continues to respond to the
demand situation in these sectors.
Other sectors are not picking up the slack despite
there being latent demand. This is compounded
by poor agricultural performance.
Exports, and increased public investment, are typically proposed to solve a structural demand problem.
But India’s growth story is not export-led. Exports
complement domestic demand but never have been
the engine of Indian growth. If this continues, then
the structural problem will not go away. Public investment is constrained by limited domestic financial
savings. About 65 per cent of the Centre’s fiscal deficit
is used to finance consumption expenditure. Tax
buoyancies cannot realistically be expected to increase
sharply when there is a growth slowdown.
Faced with a structural demand problem, the
cornerstone of growth policy should be to harness
the demand at affordable prices of those earning at least the minimum wage.
Rural India is treated as a place where we solve
the food problem, with the question of income and
demand being relegated to residual status. In addition,
growth in rural incomes (including, but not limited
to, doubling of farmers’ income) needs more macroeconomic attention.
Affordable housing is another sector where the
private sector could profitably increase economic
activity and employment, with demand for homes
that those earning the minimum wage can afford
being the focus, rather than middle-class homes in
suburban conurbations.
We make clothing in India for the rich but we
import a lot of clothing for those earning the minimum wage from Bangladesh and Vietnam. Making
the textile sector competitive to reduce net imports
from such countries would provide a powerful
demand stimulus to growth and employment.
Health and education are also areas in which there
is latent demand from a much wider base than 20
years ago. The rich now increasingly resort to health
and education imports and so the business model
based on their demand is failing. A structural shift to
meet the demand for affordable health and education
of reasonable quality for those earning the minimum
wage would increase both economic activity and
employment. The current business model fails to
meet this demand. Thus The structural demand problem arise if growth
is to be inclusive and sustainable. Supply-side constraints are very real but need to be addressed with
the demand constraint in mind.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.